Afficher la notice abrégée

dc.rights.licenseopenen_US
dc.contributor.authorFINK, C.
hal.structure.identifierGroupe de Recherche en Economie Théorique et Appliquée [GREThA]
dc.contributor.authorMIGUELEZ, Ernest
IDREF: 204287510
dc.contributor.authorRAFFO, J.
dc.date.accessioned2020-02-18T20:33:53Z
dc.date.available2020-02-18T20:33:53Z
dc.date.issued2017
dc.identifier.urihttps://oskar-bordeaux.fr/handle/20.500.12278/3518
dc.description.abstractEnIntroduction: International migration - especially of high-skilled, high-educated people - is on the rise. Accordingly, academic scholars have made efforts and great progress in better understanding the patterns of migration flows across countries and their composition and characteristics - for instance, skills and gender composition. In a similar vein, governments in high-income countries have become increasingly aware of the importance of attracting skilled labor abroad to tackle skills’ shortages and scant entrepreneurial talent. Indeed, research has documented that high-skilled immigrants make a strong contribution to their host economies (see Chapter 6). As a result, many governments have introduced selective immigration policies to increase the inward flows of knowledge workers. On their side, many sending economies - not necessarily only developing countries (EU and OECD 2016) - are struggling to retain their highly trained human capital. Further evidence on what attracts and retains knowledge workers is therefore required. This chapter contributes to the literature by studying the causes of international migration and, in particular, the determinants of the international mobility of knowledge workers, which is still an underdeveloped research avenue (Brücker et al. 2012; Ortega and Peri 2013). We make use of the original data set on migrant inventors described in detail in Chapter 4 as a proxy for knowledge workers and study their migration patterns over a long period of time. We first investigate whether knowledge migration patterns and trends can be studied within the same framework that has been applied to the international migration of all workers. To achieve this goal, we make use of the well-known gravity model of international migration (for a recent survey, see Beine et al. 2016). The theoretical foundations for the gravity approach come from Roy (1951), Sjaastad (1962), and Borjas (1987, 1989), who all build different models that formalize the decision to migrate as a function of income differentials between origin and destination economies, net of the costs of moving to another country. Recent data availability on a dyadic basis (origin-destination countries) - as commented on in Chapter 2 - has allowed researchers to empirically test these and other ideas and identify the push and pull factors of international migration.
dc.language.isoENen_US
dc.publisherCambridge University Pressen_US
dc.source.titleThe International Mobility of Talent and Innovation. New Evidence and Policy Implicationsen_US
dc.title.enDeterminants of the international mobility of knowledge workers
dc.typeChapitre d'ouvrageen_US
dc.identifier.doi10.1017/9781316795774.006en_US
dc.subject.halEconomie et finance quantitative [q-fin]en_US
dc.subject.halÉconomie et finance quantitative [q-fin]
bordeaux.page162-190en_US
bordeaux.hal.laboratoriesGroupe de Recherche en Economie Théorique et Appliquée (GREThA) - UMR 5113en_US
bordeaux.institutionUniversité de Bordeauxen_US
bordeaux.inpressnonen_US
hal.identifierhal-03141604
hal.version1
hal.date.transferred2021-02-15T12:47:49Z
hal.exporttrue
bordeaux.COinSctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.btitle=The%20International%20Mobility%20of%20Talent%20and%20Innovation.%20New%20Evidence%20and%20Policy%20Implications&rft.date=2017&rft.spage=162-190&rft.epage=162-190&rft.au=FINK,%20C.&MIGUELEZ,%20Ernest&RAFFO,%20J.&rft.genre=unknown


Fichier(s) constituant ce document

FichiersTailleFormatVue

Il n'y a pas de fichiers associés à ce document.

Ce document figure dans la(les) collection(s) suivante(s)

Afficher la notice abrégée